Shadow price

From Infogalactic: the planetary knowledge core
Jump to: navigation, search

Lua error in package.lua at line 80: module 'strict' not found.

The term "Shadow Price" or "Shadow Pricing" is used to refer to monetary values assigned to currently unknowable or difficult to calculate costs. The origin of these costs is typically due to an externalization of costs or an unwillingness to recalculate a system to account for marginal production. For example consider a firm that already has a factory full of equipment and staff. They might estimate the shadow price for a few more units of production as simply the cost of the overtime. In this manner some goods and services have near zero shadow prices, for example information goods.

Less formally, the cost of decisions made at the margin without consideration of the total cost. For example consider a trip in your car. You might estimate the shadow price of that trip by including the cost of gas; but you are unlikely to include the wear on the tires or the cost of the money you might have borrowed to purchase the car.

In constrained optimization in economics, the shadow price is the instantaneous change, per unit of the constraint, in the objective value of the optimal solution of an optimization problem obtained by relaxing the constraint. In other words, it is the marginal utility of relaxing the constraint, or, equivalently, the marginal cost of strengthening the constraint.

In a business application, a shadow price is the maximum price that management is willing to pay for an extra unit of a given limited resource.[1] For example, if a production line is already operating at its maximum 40-hour limit, the shadow price would be the maximum price the manager would be willing to pay for operating it for an additional hour, based on the benefits he would get from this change.

More formally, the shadow price is the value of the Lagrange multiplier at the optimal solution, which means that it is the infinitesimal change in the objective function arising from an infinitesimal change in the constraint. This follows from the fact that at the optimal solution the gradient of the objective function is a linear combination of the constraint function gradients with the weights equal to the Lagrange multipliers. Each constraint in an optimization problem has a shadow price or dual variable.

The value of the shadow price can provide decision-makers with insights into problems. For instance if a constraint limits the amount of labor available to you to 40 hours per week, the shadow price will tell you how much you should be willing to pay for an additional hour of labor. If your shadow price is $10 for the labor constraint, for instance, you should pay no more than $10 an hour for additional labor. Labor costs of less than $10/hour will increase the objective value; labor costs of more than $10/hour will decrease the objective value. Labor costs of exactly $10 will cause the objective function value to remain the same.

Shadow Pricing in Investing

Money market funds are always prices with a nominal value of $1.00 per share. That $1.00 price however does not accurately reflect the value of the fund. The Shadow Price refers to the amortized value of rather than the assigned market value.[2]

Shadow Price on a Balance Sheet

In advance of adequate regulation or market pricing for some commodity items conservative organizations will place on their balance sheets a value they believe to be an accurate reflection of the value of those items to their operations. This is common for companies with a large carbon footprint or water footprint. As an example Microsoft has placed a $27/ton price on its carbon emissions which is then billed to the P&L of its individual business units and used to fund the company's renewable energy and efficiency programs.[3] [4]

Shadow Price of Foreign Exchange

Illustration #1

Suppose a consumer faces prices \,\! p_1,p_2 and is endowed with income \,\!m, then the consumer's problem is: 
\max \{\,\!u(x_1,x_2)\mbox{ } :\mbox{ } p_1x_1+p_2x_2=m\}. Forming the Lagrangian auxiliary function \,\! L(x_1,x_2,\lambda):= u(x_1,x_2)+\lambda(m-p_1x_1-p_2x_2), taking first order conditions and solving for its saddle point we obtain \,\! x^*_1\mbox{, }x^*_2\mbox{, }\lambda^* which satisfy:

 \lambda^*=\frac{\frac{\partial u(x^*_1,x^*_2)}{\partial x_1}}{p_1}= \frac{\frac{\partial u(x^*_1,x^*_2)}{\partial x_2}}{p_2}

This gives us a clear interpretation of the Lagrange Multiplier in the context of consumer maximization. If the consumer is given an extra dollar (the budget constraint is relaxed) at the optimal consumption level where the marginal utility per dollar for each good is equal to \,\! \lambda^* as above, then the change in maximal utility per dollar of additional income will be equal to \,\! \lambda^* since at the optimum the consumer gets the same amount of marginal utility per dollar from spending his additional income on either goods. In this case the shadow price concept does not carry much importance because the objective function (utility) and the constraint (income) are measured in different units.

Illustration #2

Holding prices fixed, if we define

 U(p_1,p_2,m) = \max \{\,\!u(x_1,x_2)\mbox{ } :\mbox{ } p_1x_1+p_2x_2=m\},

then we have the identity

\,\! U(p_1,p_2,m)=u(x_1^*(p_1,p_2,m),x_2^*(p_1,p_2,m)) ,

where \,\! x_1^*(\cdot,\cdot,\cdot),x_2^*(\cdot,\cdot,\cdot) are the demand functions, i.e.  x_i^*(p_1,p_2,m) = \arg\max \{\,\!u(x_1,x_2)\mbox{ } :\mbox{ } p_1x_1+p_2x_2=m\} \mbox{ for } i=1,2

Now define the optimal expenditure function

\,\! E(p_1,p_2,m) =p_1x_1^*(p_1,p_2,m)+p_2x_2^*(p_1,p_2,m)

Assume differentiability and that \,\! \lambda^* is the solution at \,\! p_1,p_2,m, then we have from the multivariate chain rule:

\,\! \frac{\partial U}{\partial m} =\frac{\partial u}{\partial x_1}\frac{\partial x_1^*}{\partial m} + \frac{\partial u}{\partial x_2}\frac{\partial x_2^*}{\partial m} =\lambda^* p_1\frac{\partial x_1^*}{\partial m} + \lambda^* p_2 \frac{\partial x_2^*}{\partial m}=\lambda^* \left(p_1\frac{\partial x_1^*}{\partial m} +  p_2 \frac{\partial x_2^*}{\partial m} \right) =\lambda^* \frac{\partial E}{\partial m}

Now we may conclude that

\,\! \lambda^* = \frac{\partial U/\partial m}{\partial E/\partial m} \approx \frac{\Delta \mbox{Optimal Utility }}{\Delta \mbox{Optimal Expenditure}}

This again gives the obvious interpretation, one extra dollar of optimal expenditure will lead to \,\! \lambda^* units of optimal utility.

Control theory

In optimal control theory, the concept of shadow price is reformulated as costate equations, and one solves the problem by minimization of the associated Hamiltonian via Pontryagin's minimum principle.

See also

Further reading

  • Lua error in package.lua at line 80: module 'strict' not found.
  • Lua error in package.lua at line 80: module 'strict' not found.
  • Lua error in package.lua at line 80: module 'strict' not found.

References

  1. Shadow Price: Definition and Much More from Answers.com
  2. Definition of 'Shadow Price' from Investopedia.com
  3. "Carbon Shadow Pricing" from www.ClimateMoneyPolicy.com
  4. "Carbon Shadow Pricing" Via www.LinkedIn.com